The topics covered on this page may include legal and
regulatory developments affecting loan origination and mortgage creation,
consumer protection, and enforcement of creditors’ rights. This page may also note
key developments in some areas of law that are closely related to housing
lending and necessary for development of a sound housing finance market, such
as regulation of financial institutions, mortgage securities, and market
participants, and are covered in more detail on other topic pages of this site.
Current laws and regulations of interest will be noted
mostly on the individual country pages, but new laws and regulatory acts of particular
significance may be noted here as we become aware of them, along with proposed
or ongoing legal reform initiatives in various countries. The emphasis will be
on issues in emerging mortgage markets, but developments in and materials from
developed markets will be covered for the lessons and models they may provide.
As with other theme pages on this site, and because
of the rapidly developing legal environment in many countries today, this page
would benefit from advice and materials from readers in all of the countries Hofinet
seeks to serve; all are encouraged to send updates on their legal regimes along
with laws, regulations and policies newly adopted or under consideration.
Legal
and Regulatory Issues in Housing Finance
Most housing loans are secured by mortgage of the
home constructed, acquired or improved with the proceeds of the loan. While
there are other forms of housing lending–housing microfinance, for example,
which appears to be developing rapidly today–and other forms of loan security,
these appear to comprise a relatively minor part of the total volume of housing
lending. Indeed, most banking regulators insist on high-quality collateral for
housing loans, even more so today as the effects of the 2007 mortgage market
crisis in developed economies continue to be felt.[1]
Accordingly, the essential laws of housing finance are concerned with the
creation and enforcement of mortgage liens, and the depth and breadth of
housing finance markets in countries may be related to the nature and quality
of their laws for establishing and enforcing creditors’ rights under mortgages.
Theory
of Mortgage Collateral
Laws and regulations can be either incentives or
disincentives to lending and borrowing. The theory of collateral is that by
providing an efficient means of recapturing an investment, the costs and risks
of housing lending are reduced. In particular, shorter time periods and greater
certainty in realization of collateral eliminates risks such as lost interest
and loss of principal from deterioration in collateral value due to, for
example, unpaid taxes or lack of property maintenance. Simplification of
enforcement procedures also may tend to reduce transaction costs. Reduction of transaction
costs and financial risks means greater proceeds from sale of collateral, which
benefits not only the creditor, but in theory the debtor also. Reduced costs
and greater certainty in enforcement are believed to result in lower risk
premiums in interest rates, and greater willingness of creditors to make more
credit available for housing construction and acquisition, either going deeper
into the socio-economic strata or offering larger loans.
Some
Empirical Evidence
Arriving at compelling conclusions regarding the relationship
between the efficiency of enforcing creditors’ rights and the availability and
cost of credit has not been easy. Finding data that permit cross-country
comparisons, defining the appropriate indicators, and controlling for the host
of external variables that affect credit markets and interest rates are only a
few of the problems. Nevertheless, there is a body of empirical evidence that
the theory is correct, and that an efficient system of creditors’ rights
increases societal welfare.[2]
Modern studies have suggested a strong relationship between the quality of
laws, the efficiency of law enforcement concerning creditors’ and contract
rights and the availability and cost of credit to businesses and households. Moreover,
while much of this research initially focused on the laws themselves, it has become
clear that the quality of the laws and quality of enforcement can be independent
variables and that good laws will have more effect when they are efficiently
enforced. A few examples of these findings include:
·In a 2004 study
of loans to legal entities in 48 countries ranked on the basis of the strength
of creditors’ legal rights, Bae and Goyal found that banks lend more, over
longer terms, and charge lower rates on loans to borrowers in countries where
creditors’ rights are well protected and efficiently enforced.[3]
The study suggests that although strong creditors’ rights in the laws decreased
interest rates, more efficient enforcement of contracts in the courts not only
decreased interest rates but increased loan size and lengthened loan maturities
as well.
·In a 1990 study
of mortgage loan enforcement in the United States, Clauretie and Herzog found
that the characteristics of the mortgage law had an effect on the losses
incurred by mortgage creditors. Creditors’ losses were lower in states that
allowed non-judicial enforcement of a mortgage and personal judgments against borrowers
for the amounts not repaid from sale of the mortgaged property, and higher in
states that established long periods for debtors to redeem the property after
foreclosure sale.[4] Similar
studies in the U.S. market have found that long redemption periods result in
higher average interest rates on all mortgage loans in the jurisdiction in
which the long periods apply.
·In a 2005 study
using a sample of loans in 43 countries, Qian and Strahan estimated how various
bank loan terms–including interest rates and maturity–may be affected by a
country’s legal and institutional characteristics.[5]
They concluded from their study that where creditor protections are strong,
bank loans tend to have longer maturities and lower interest rates.
·In a 2008 study
that focused on legal development in 12 Eastern European countries in
transition from socialism, Haselmann, Pistor and Vig showed that the strength
of laws on collateral, including the ability to efficiently pledge and register
a pledge of real and personal property, significantly affected the quantity of
credit available in those countries, and suggested that the increase in lending
was greater for ordinary households than for business enterprises. The authors
speculated that this result arises because more efficient collateral laws allow
creditors to compensate for the lack of clear information regarding the credit-worthiness
of individual households.[6]
·In a 1991
study, Xavier Freixas showed that in Europe the average cost as well as the
duration of judicial procedures required to repossess pledged assets are
inversely related to the amount of funds available to finance consumption and
housing acquisitions by households.[7]
·In a 2003 study
for the World Bank, Laeven and Majnoni investigated the effect of judicial efficiency
on banks’ interest rate spreads for a large cross-section of 106 countries.
They defined the interest rate spread as the difference between the average
lending rate of the banks and the average interest rate the banks paid their
depositors. They compared the interest rate spreads with standard indicators of
judicial efficiency and the quality of the rule of law, including an index that
takes into account the time taken to deliver judicial decisions. They found
that after controlling for a number of other country characteristics, judicial
efficiency, in addition to inflation, is the main determinant of interest rate
spreads across countries. That is, the perceived performance of the judiciary
as measured by various indicators contributes directly to the difference
between the interest rate banks borrow at and the rate they lend at. Poorer
performance on the judicial efficiency indicators led to higher relative
interest rates. They concluded that in addition to improving the overall
macroeconomic climate in a country, judicial reforms, through better
enforcement of legal contracts, are critical to lowering the cost of bank
credit for households and firms.[8]
·Studies
indicate that even within a single country, financial outcomes vary across
regions that have the same laws but different court efficiency. Bianco et al.
(2005) found that in Italian provinces with longer trials or larger backlogs of
pending trials, credit is less widely available than elsewhere in Italy and the
interest rate spread between bank lending rates and deposit rates is greater.[9]
Relationship of Length of Trials to Amount of
Credit Granted by Banks in Regions of Italy
Source: Magda Bianco & Tullio Jappelli & Marco Pagano, 2001. “Courts and Banks: Effects of Judicial Enforcement on Credit Markets,” CSEF Working Papers 58, Centre for Studies in Economics
and Finance (CSEF), University of Naples, Italy, revised 09 Apr. 2002.
As a general proposition, there appears to be a
consensus that poor legal fundamentals–in particular the inability to create
and enforce a mortgage lien in a reasonably efficient and cost-effective
manner–leads to increased risk of lending, higher risk premiums in loan
interest rates, higher transactions costs and markets that are both smaller and
shallower in terms of income strata served. Regardless of the statistical
proofs, it seems self-evident that any rules or procedures that increase the
risks and costs associated with lending will have a price, and the question is,
what form does the price take, and who is paying it? The price may be in higher
interest rates or less credit than would otherwise be available, or may be in
encouraging the use of alternative systems of securing credit that provide
fewer formal legal protections to debtors.
Lack
of legal guidance
There are several ways in which inadequate legal
regimes may affect the breadth and depth of housing finance markets. One has
been lack of clear legal guidance for lenders in the laws of some emerging
country markets. Lenders are reluctant to be pioneers in situations where the
laws are unclear and there is lack of legal precedent, as is the case in many
emerging markets. This concern seems to be decreasing as better mortgage laws
are adopted and experience with housing finance is gained by lenders, borrowers
and courts. Nevertheless, in new markets some ambiguities persist. Typical
areas of ambiguity may include grounds for default and enforcement of claims,
judicial discretion to suspend or refuse execution, permitted defenses to
lender’s claims, legal priorities among parties, and obtaining orders of
eviction and possession of mortgage property.
Delays
and non-judicial process
A main problem may be long delays and high costs in
realization of creditors’ rights. Delays are a function of the laws and often
of enforcement of the laws by the courts, which may be reluctant to enforce
claims against residential property and inclined to tolerate long delays on
procedural grounds. This is true not only in emerging markets but in many
developed markets as well. It is perhaps noteworthy how many countries of the
EU, for example, specifically allow courts to suspend execution of a mortgage
for a period of time, in their discretion, for the benefit of the borrower on
grounds of social protection.
Long delays in collection have in some countries led
to use of alternative devices to secure housing loans and avoid the complexities
and inefficiencies of mortgages. These alternatives include lease-purchase and installment
sales contracts, where the title to the property remains in the name of the
lending institution; or equitable mortgages or mortgage by deed, where the borrower
assigns the deed to the lender; personal guarantees; and use of back-dated personal
checks, which could in earlier times expose a borrower to criminal penalties in
the event of default (and which have been outlawed today in many counties). Mortgage
alternatives may in many cases be more efficient for the lender and arguably
have increased the volume of housing lending in some countries, but they are
not necessarily good for borrowers, as they often lack the basic protections of
borrowers’ rights and equities that are found in mortgage laws. Despite its
obvious drawbacks, one thing that can be said of mortgage law is that it
provides significant legal protection to the rights and interests of debtors that
other forms of security may not.
An important approach to procedural delay has been
to remove mortgage enforcement from the courts through non-judicial enforcement
procedures such as lender power of sale or fiduciary trust arrangements. In the
former the lender itself can proceed to sell a property without going to court,
subject to statutory rules, and in the latter an independent trustee or
fiduciary such as a notary or bailiff can take action on behalf of the lender
without court action. Understandably, non-judicial enforcement of mortgages is
a matter of some controversy in many countries, and even in the United States a
large number of states will not allow it. In some places there may be a sense
that banks are predatory and will institute unjustified enforcement actions to
profit from resale of the property, though there has been little evidence of
that, and much more evidence that taking and selling property is the last
resort for most lenders and in fact often results in significant losses. (The
recent mortgage market crisis in the United States may throw a different light
on this issue by suggesting that actual predatory behavior of lending
institutions is irrelevant if the lenders are negligent and even recklessly
indifferent with respect to their loan underwriting practices.)
Similarly, the laws of most countries today require
some sort of public auction sale of mortgaged property, based on the
expectation that public sales are more transparent and in theory should result
in market prices for auctioned property. In fact the evidence to support those
propositions is also lacking and good arguments can be made that private sale
through normal market mechanism may provide benefits to both lenders and
borrowers.
Stephen B. Butler is a Principal Research Scientist in the International Projects Department of NORC at the University of Chicago.He has advised international donor agencies and ministries, central banks and regulatory commissions in 30 transitional and developing countries in 5 regions, focusing on land reform and administration, housing and housing finance, and mortgage market development.